WTO: Agreement on Agriculture
-- Srilata Swaminathan
It should come as no surprise that that the lead up to the Cancun Ministerial meeting in September of this year is going the same way that all previous WTO meetings have. The developed countries continue to utilise WTO as a means to maintain and further their stranglehold over the global economy. Nowhere are the intentions of the developed countries spelt out as clearly as in the new text on modalities for the Agreement on Agriculture (AoA) by Stuart Harbinson, the Chairperson of the Special Session of the Committee on Agriculture. Finalisation of the modalities is an important step as it will be the basis of the AoA and what gets left out cannot be added later. So, it becomes very important that developing countries make sure that their needs are addressed.
Item |
Cost of Production |
Export Price |
1. Wheat | $ 6.24 per bushel | $ 3.50 per bushel |
2. Soya Bean | $ 6.96 per bushel | $ 4.93 per bushel |
3. Maize | $ 3.47 per bushel | $ 2.28 per bushel |
4. Cotton | $ 0.93 per bushel | $ 0.39 per bushel |
5. Rice | $18.66 per bushel | $14.55 per bushel |
Harbinson’s text came out mid-February and already many developing countries
and international organisations are up in arms against it. Firstly, Harbinson’s
draft addresses only those issues that were in the Uruguay Round such as (i)
tariffs (ii) domestic support and (iii) export subsidy; it does not attempt
to go beyond that. It takes no cognisance of those issues that are priorities
for the developing countries and so the underlying inequalities in the structure
of agricultural trade rules remain unchanged. It is precisely these inequalities
that are the main reason that farmers in the third world are facing hardships
and also the reason that unsustainable methods of agriculture continue to be
encouraged in developing countries.
Item |
Dumping in 1995 |
Dumping in 2001 |
1. Wheat |
23% |
44% |
2. Soya Bean |
9% |
29% |
3. Maize |
11% |
33% |
4. Cotton |
17% |
57% |
Even though the text tries to give some concessions to developing countries
such as concepts like ‘strategic products’ for food security, the
protection of small farm families and for rural development, it remains extremely
superficial and ineffectual on these fronts. In fact, the text actually enhances
the distortions, imbalances and handicaps faced by poor nations.
The text brazenly continues not only to defend but even legalise the subsidies
being given by the Developed countries to their farmers and allows them to continue,
in one form or another. All the domestic supports given to their farmers under
‘green box’ and ‘blue box’ subsidies will continue,
some will be phased out in five years, others in nine years and some will go
on indefinitely! These are subsidies that are, supposedly, not trade distorting
and cover a wide range of domestic support to farmers such as giving farmers
specialised training, environment and soil protection, payments to farmers to
leave land unploughed etc. etc. But this is a fallacy as these domestic supports
definitely are trade distorting. Combined with export subsidies farmers in the
Developed countries are able to export their produce well below the actual cost
of production and hence undercut the world market prices in their own favour.
The text thinks it is being equitable by allowing developing countries to have
the same subsidies but in its magnanimity it forgets that developing countries
do not have the means to give them to their farmers. While in the US these subsidies
are only 2-3% of their GDP, in India or any other third world country the same
subsidies to their farmers would be more that 50% of their GDP!
Furthermore, the text allows the Developed countries to use high export subsidies
to boost up the export of their agriculture products. The OECD countries give
a whopping $400 billion in annual subsidies to their farmers. Contrary to the
claims of the WTO, which maintains that the Developed countries have reduced
agricultural subsidies, we see that the US Farm Bill for 2002 shows an increase
of $83 billion! African countries are facing a loss of $250 million each year
due to the subsidised export rates in the US. The table below shows the extent
of US export subsidies to their farmers so that they are able to export their
produce well below the actual cost of production without suffering any loss
in five major crops in the year 2001.
One of the greatest concerns of developing countries is the subject of dumping
by the Developed countries. Dumping of exports is a major way in which our farmers
are being hit, are unable to sell their produce, are being forced to cut back
in cultivation etc. The only effective way for countries like India to put an
end to dumping is through Quantitative Restrictions (QRs), which are more effective
than raising tariffs. But countries like India have been forced to remove all
QRs so that Developed countries can have unfettered access to their markets.
While one of the prime objectives of the WTO is to end practices like dumping,
what we are actually seeing is the exact opposite, as the table below shows:
Harbinson reiterates article 4.2 of the AoA text in wanting all developing countries
to stop using QRs or tariffs to counter dumping! Developing countries must see
that this article is dropped, that all domestic support and export subsidies
in developed countries are eliminated as soon as possible and until this happens
they, the developing countries, should have the right to continue with QRs.
A further example of how the rich are favoured over the poor is in the provision
for Special Safeguards (SSG), which is a provision whereby a country can take
action to protect its farmers against surges of import and fall of prices, and
these are available only for the developed countries. While most of the developing
countries, which have overriding need for SSG, are denied this provision, developed
countries can use these provisions for another 5-7 years! Thus the developed
countries that distorted trade by applying non-tariff measures earlier and converted
them to equivalent tariffs in the Uruguay Round continue to get the benefit
of the SSG, while the developing countries that did not apply such trade distorting
measures earlier and thus did not have the necessity of conversion of such measures
to tariffs will continue to be denied the use of SSG.
The delegates from many countries, Brazil, Barbados, the Philippines and India
made clear their unhappiness and disappointment with Harbinson’s text.
However, many critics feel that what is needed is a totally new text that will
firmly address the inequalities and distortions in the AoA.
On 13 March the Indian People’s Campaign Against WTO held a convention
in Delhi outlining the problems of third world countries in the Cancun Meetings
to be held from 10-14 September where the rich nations want to push through
the ‘new issues’ such as investment. Competition, policy, government
Procurement and trade facilitation which will further their imperialist agenda.
It was decided that in Delhi a massive rally would be held on 26 August against
the Cancun ministerial meeting of WTO. All over the world public opinion is
being created and people are being prepared, educated and mobilised to derail
the Cancun Meeting.
References:
‘NGOs call for Rejection of WTO Agriculture Modalities Paper’ by
Goh Chien Yen,
Third World Network Report.
AgBioIndia bulletins of the Forum for Biotechnology & Food Security.
WTO & Agriculture, The Cancun Series No.1 – RFSTE/Navdanya.
WTO Virodhi Bharitiya Jan Abhiyan’s Press Release: 13.3.’03.